The Principle of Variable Geometry In Intergration




Introduction:

Variable geometry and multi-level governance are just two terms used to describe the changing nature of territorial politics within the European Union. The creation of the EU, and the associated process of economic, political and social integration which has accompanied it, has changed the nature of nation state and sub-national politics as it had been known for at least two centuries.

This essay seeks to evaluate some of the changes that have occurred, particularly over the last two decades, and which have resulted particularly in changing forms of sub-national politics within the EU. Most specifically it will examine the extent to which the essential distinction between Northern and Southern European styles of local politics (see inter alia Page and Goldsmith: 1986; Goldsmith: 2000; John:2001) is being undermined by the process of European integration and policy Europeanisation to which Raedelli makes reference in this volume[i]. Last in  this context it seeks to evaluate briefly current explanations offered of political integration within the European Union.

The essay will suggest that key economic changes, some associated with globalisation, others with the introduction of the Single Market, others with the process of deregulation that has taken place over the last twenty years, have posed European cities and regions with a constantly changing and often different set of challenges, opportunities and constraints as they seek to manage the turbulent environments in which they operate. It will also suggest that the political dynamic of the EU, especially through the emergence of a strong regional policy, has encouraged forms of cooperative sub-national politics which have subtly changed both national intergovernmental relationships and those between the EU and nation states.

Whilst recent developments may have re-asserted the primacy of the nation state within the EU political system, the essay argues that further expansion of the EU means that the system of territorial politics in Europe remains unstable and continual subject to change, especially at the sub-national level. In particular, whilst the old styles of Northern and Southern local politics remain, new cross-national networks of local and regional governments, reflecting the experience of regional policy, together with the way in which different cities and regions seek to be increasingly competitive in a global market, means that territorial politics within the EU will remain unstable in the forseeable future.

The essay will conclude by evaluating the extent to which ideas such as variable geometry and multi -level governance remain useful concepts in aiding our understanding of the processes of change through which EU territorial politics are currently passing.

Conceptualising EU integration:

As a starting point it is useful to review the different ways in which the EU integration has been conceptualised by observers over recent years. Effectively there have been three main approaches. The first, dominant in the early life of the EU, and elements of which are important even today, perceives the process of European integration as an international regime, designed by sovereign states, who seek to regulate the development of economic and political interdependence through a process of international collaboration. Given that the EU is a treaty based organisation – as distinct to a federal or confederal system such as the United States, Canada of Germany – it is first and foremost a state centred organisation, in which the member states are at the centre of the decision making process.[ii] As a result change comes about incrementally, with the most significant changes brought about through a success of new Treaties such as those agreed in Maastricht (1992); Amsterdam (1995) and Nice (2000). Decisions on policies and program, finance and regulatory regimes are effectively ratified at the periodic meetings of the Council of Ministers, at which heads of state have frequently negotiated different terms to those originally proposed by the Commission, or have negotiated opt out arrangements (Social Charter), won specific deals (Thatcher and the budgetary rebate) or exercised a veto on proposals.  For those (e.g. Hoffman 1982) who argue that the EU conforms to such a model, control remains vested in the nation states and changes depend on voluntary cooperation and bargaining between powerful member states. One possible example in which this process can be seen is the Nice agreement, under which it was the interest of the big states (eg Germany, France and Britain) which dominated the final form the treaty took. As writers such as Hooghe (1996a, 177) suggest, decision making under this model is effectively elitist, closed, opaque and not readily accountable – giving rise to a form of institutional arrangements probably best characterised be de Gaulle’s phrase a “Europe de Patries” rather than some other form of arrangement.

Whilst such a characterisation of the EU might have been valid in its early years and up until the early eighties, a number of factors have undermined the state centred model more recently. First, there have been changes in the decision making rules, with the introduction of Qualified Majority Voting on an increasing number of issue areas,  thus negating the veto power of nation states in these areas. Second, the European Parliament now has a greater say in decision-making than in the past, especially over the budget. Third, the emergence of the European Court as the arbiter on EU legal matters, in which its decisions are accepted by member states, means that nation states no longer have sovereignty over many areas formerly associated with state activities. Fourth, the growing process of ‘government by regulation’ through the regulatory decisions of the Commission and of EU agencies again undermines the position of national governments. In other words, whilst nation states remain the most important actors at the centre of EU decision-making, their position is less strong than it was twenty years ago.


The second model, often employed in more normative debates about the EU, is essentially a federalist one, in which the EU is a supranational state. It is usually described in the academic literature as an intergovernmental model: in this model political decisions depend on the relationships between different levels of government, and on how the powers and functions allocated to the different levels operate in practice in both formal and informal ways. Normatively this model comes closest to that propounded by the advocates of a federal Europe, or most often derided by Eurosceptics. Its strongest advocate could be found in Jacques Delors during his time as President of the Commission, who thought of the EU as having a strong supranational core (i.e. the Commission) working with weakened nation states and a strengthened, but fragmented, regional periphery. This model is Delors ‘Europe of the Regions’ writ large, giving rise to a contested hierarchy as regions compete amongst themselves and with the nation states over territorial representation, but with a powerful Commission at the centre acting effectively as the policy arbiter, given its key position as the policy initiator.

Such a view of the EU was more prevalent in the late eighties and early 1990s, during a period when regional policy and its associated expenditure levels were growing in importance. During this period the Commission – as the supranational body, tended to promote the regions and sub-national government generally, seeking to mobilise them on a functional basis around a series of specific European wide issues (Tommel, 1998).  And as regional policy grew in importance so did the development of widespread functional and territorial networks seeking to represent regional and local interests and to influence Commission policy – indeed some of these networks were specifically encouraged by the Commission itself in policy areas dealing with regional, environmental, innovation / technology transfer and ITC issues. Cooke and Morgan: 1998; Simmie 2000).

Development of an EU model along these lines would see a more pluralistic and competitive decision making process, albeit one in which the Commission was central in what would otherwise be a highly fragmented process. More open and accessible than the state centred model, it would be no more accountable, however, as decisions would still be taken behind the closed doors and in the corridors of the Commission.

A third model emerged in middle nineties which characterised the EU as a system of multi-level governance, as developed in the writings of authors such as Gary Marks and Lisbet Hooghe (see for example Marks, Scharpf, Schmitter and Streek, 1996; Hooghe1996a; 1996b and 1998; Marks and Hooghe 2001).  Hooghe characterised this system as a ‘Europe with the Regions’ as distinct to Delors’ ‘Europe of the Regions’. Here it is not only the Commission, European Parliament, the Court of Justice, EU agencies and national governments who are involved, but also regional and other sub-national levels as well. The result is a system of decision-making in which there are multiple access points, multiple opportunities to exercise influence and pressure, and multiple places at which decisions are made. No predominant territorial principle guides decision making, there is extensive sub-national mobilisation across all sectors (including the third or voluntary sector) and the different actors play a series of what are perhaps best thought of as grantsmanship games. Decision making in this case is described by Hooghe (1996a) as “pluralist with an elitist bias” in that only actors with valuable resources can participate – in other words the playing field is not a level one for all participants, and nation states can no longer act as gatekeepers able to close off the European policy agenda and political arena.
This multi-level governance model has attracted considerable attention in recent years (see inter alia Smith; 1995; 1997; Benz), as well as some criticism.
Conceptualising Europeanisation:
Here it is easiest to follow Raedelli (this volume), even at the risk of simplification.  First and foremost, Europeanisation refers to the process by which increasing numbers of policy arenas have taken on a European dimension as the process of European integration has developed.[iii]  Such policy arenas are characterised by the presence of a wide variety of actors, be they the Commission and its directorates, national and sub-national governments and agencies, and national and trans-national interest groups, brought together into a complex policy network. Environmental policy provides an easy example – in the early sixties there was little discussion of environmental policy at EU level – today it is a major area for discussion amongst all the types of actors listed above and for EU regulation. Regional policy, our focus here, was largely a national matter until the early to mid eighties, but has been a major strand of EU policy since that time – and was what brought sub-national units and their representative bodies to Brussels in such large numbers.. Agricultural policy has always been Europeanised ever since the CAP came into being: when Britain joined the National Farmers Union quickly transferred its attentions from Whitehall to Brussels. On  the other hand social policy has been somewhat marginalised at the European level, with more change probably being achieved through indirect regulation (for example in relation to the working hours directive) than direct intervention in processes of income redistribution or the provision of health care services. Both the latter remain by and large firmly in the hands of national governments, though with some debate at the EU level or some work undertaken within the Commission.
Second, Europeanisation can be used to describe the process of regulation by which a wide variety of policy areas are subject to regulations and directives agreed in Brussels, largely at the behest of the Commission and accepted by member state governments – another form of policy making. This process has been well-described by authors such as Majone (1996) and Cram (1997), and involves  sub-national governments in the implementation and/or enforcement of a growing number of such regulations across an increasing number of fields ranging from health and safety through the environment to consumer standards and contracts.

Third, it is also clear that the Europeanisation of policy arenas varies over time and with the agenda of the EU and its institutions. For example, the debate within theEU between widening and deepening during the 1990s has largely been resolved in favour of widening, by bringing in Central and East European countries at some future point. Given also decisions to limit the EU budget or at least to set it within certain constraints, then changes in othere areas of EU policy making are likely to follow. Top of the list must be the reform of the CAP, though this will no doubt be difficult to achieve, given the heavy involvement of many present Southern European EU members and of some prospective members in agriculture. As we shall see regional policy has already undergone some changes, and the area of ITC policy has moved from one of a concern with IT literacy in the early 1990s to one of communications regulation/deregulation today. Similarly, with the creation of the single European Market, transport policy has moved up the EU agenda, with concerns to de-regulate road haulage, to improve transport infrastructure across the EU, and to improve competition in air transport.[iv]

Sub-national government in the EU Context:
Sub-national government in the EU member countries has also changed markedly during the lifetime of the EEC/EU.  One can identify a number of pressures which have sought ot bring about change, most being designed to bring about some form of decentralisation within nation states. First, there has been pressure from below – what Loughlin (2000; Keating and Loughlin: 1997) would call regionalism, in which sub-national territories, generally at the regional level, have pressured national governments to give such territories (usually claiming some nationalist status) a greater degree of autonomy. Two cases are readily apparent – the emergence of the autonomous communities in Spain, especially Catalonia and the Basque region, and the establishment of the Flemish and Wallonia regions in Belgium. In other cases this pressure has been a less direct cause of decentralisation – as with devolution to Scotland and Wales in Britain, or has met with less success – such as the pressure for recognition by Bretons in Brittany in France. This kind of meso development can be thought as a process of bottom up regionalism.

The second pressure has come from central governments themselves, generally in the form of a gradual transfer of functions from central to lower tier governments, and generally recognising a strengthening of the intermediate or meso tier (Sharpe 1993). Scandinavian reforms, for example, have seen such functions of health and social welfare move down towards a strengthened county tier, and this move has also been accompanied by a reduction in the number of municipal or bottom tier governments (Albæk, Rose, Strómberg and Ståhlberg, 1991). In the early seventies Britain followed down a similar path, though later moved in the opposite direction as under succesive Conservative governments the British political system became increasingly centralised, a trend reversed in parts under the Blair Labour governments since 1997. France, with the decentralisation reforms under Mitterand, went down a similar path in the eighties, with the establishment of new ( largely weak) regional tier, a strengthening of the departmental influence over the activities of the communes (especially encouraging the development of inter-communal cooperation) and generally strengthening the position of urban agglomerations and large cities (Michel:1999).

Third, pressure has been external to the nation state and reflects both increasing globalisation and changes encouraged through the activities in the EU, especially the development of regional policies by the Commission from the late eighties onwards. It was this latter development which essentially gave rise to the multi-level goverance model (Hooghe 1996), and it is a development which forms the substantive focus of this chapter.

However, even in this latter context, sub-national governments found in the long-standing federal systems in the EU have also undergone some change. Austria and Germany provide the examples. In both cases, it is the intermediate tier which is strong and often influential in negotiations on EU matters. In the case of Germany for example, Hesse (1991) argues that intergovernmental relaitons within the then West Germany took the form of a cooperative federalism. Benz (2000) examining later experience in the mid-nineties highlights the extent to which the German lander varied in the way in which they dealt with things European.  In Austria (add)

What has happenned at the EU level to bring about a what is effectively a fourth tier to the intergovernmental relationship?. First, there has been the general trend towards a more globalised economy, with the resultant loosening ties between place and capital, the rise of multi-national companies, worldwide shifts in manufacturing activity and capacity, and changing technologies.[v] All of these place nation states and their sub-national levels under pressure, as regions and cities compete to maintain their place in the overall economic hierarchy, seek to become more innovative and to find ways in which they can compete in the global market place. (Cook and Morgan: 1998; Storper: 1997; ) At the EU level, this process of change has resulted in the processes of European integration and Europeanisation of policies gaining pace, especially in the years up to the Maastricht Treaty. If that point in time brought about a slowing down of formal processes of deepening  (integration) rather than widening or extending the EU to the East, it has not stopped Europeanisation completely, and in the years before, integration moved on quite rapidly. Four main sources of these processes are apparent, driven essentially by moves towards the introduction of the Single European Market, essentially  the EU response to the  economic globalisation processes just discussed. First, there was acceptance of the principle of subsidiarity, adopted in the Maastricht Treaty, under which things are (supposedly) done at the lowest possible level of government within the EU. Second, there has been an increase in the process of decision making by regulation within the EU, under which the Commission has been able to issue a large number of directives which essentially change the way in which a considerable number of policy actions are effectively determined – for example in areas such as consumer protection; contracting; environmental control; emplyoment law, and health and safety. 
Third, in many cases these areas have been further Europeanised by decisions of the European Court of Justice (ECJ).  As Hooghe and Marks (2001: 26-27) argue the ECJ ‘has transformed the European legal order in a supranational direction.’ In so doing, it has promoted European integration by establishing that the Treaties on which the EU is based and through its own decisions are legally superior to those of national courts, ie establshing the supremacy of European over national laws. These latter have also accepted Article 234 (ex.77) of the Treaty of Rome which allows them to seek ECJ guidance on cases involving Community law, guidance which is rearly rejected. If such guidance is accepted, then other national courts usually accept the decision as a precedent, so that effectively ECJ rulings bind nation states. Yet the ECJ is not completely autonomous, since it depnds on others – such as the Commission, lower courts or other private actors bringing cases before it. Areas such as equal rights, employment and consumer protection are all themes in which the ECJ has been active and with impacts, inter alia,  affecting sub-national governments.[vi]
Last but for our purposes a major point of focus, certain policy areas (regional, urban, innovation/exploitation) have had a predominantly sub-national focus, being implemented at regional or local levels. In the case of regional policy, the involvement of sub-national levels has been heightened through the adoption of the partnership principle, in which proposals for regional funding are developed on a partnerhsip basis between the differnet levels of government and with cross sector partnerships at the appropriate regional level, and where the implementation of the regional programme is largely undertaken at the regional level and monitored at both national and EU levels. The same policy focus has applied to some other policy arenas – IT, urban and innovation policy being cases in point, though all of these have had a link to regional policy

EU Regional Policy and Sub-National Government:
The last twenty years have seen the development of an extensive regional policy within the EU, largely designed to promote the cohesion of the union. What has been the key to this cohesion process has been the use of the EU’s structural funds to aid the less developed/ economic declining regions to help overcome their difficulties. That the more prosperous parts of the EU have continued to grow, and that the gap between the richest and poorest regions has not necessarily narrowed , is to some extent irrelevant here – what is important is that EU regional policy and the structural funds have been of significant benefit to some parts of the EU ( especially countries like Ireland, Spain and Portugal) and have changed the relationship between different levels of government within the EU and within the member states generally across the board.(Tommel: 1997;  In some case, arguably, the process has helped, whereas in others the impact has been marginal or even negative. What is also clear from a raft of research is that the reaction of different regions and localities has been different – in some cases regions, cities and municipalities have taken advantage of regional policy to draw down significant funds and to heighten their political status within the national and European political systems, whereas in other cases almost the opposite has been true. (Bullman: 1994; Balme: 1995; Rhodes: 1995; Smith:1995; Heinelt and Smith: 1996; Goldsmith and Klaussen: 1997; Jeffrey: 1997;Le Gales and Lequesne: 1997; Desideri and C and Sanantonio V (1996)  Add to this the use of funds to promote cross border cooperation through the INTERREG programme, and one finds new spaces/territorities beginning to emerge slowly.

This variable reaction is not simply because the Commission, in implementing regional policy, has defined eligibility criteria which exclude some sub-national units whilst including others, a point to which we shall return. Rather has it to do with the way in which different countries have sought to operate the EU regional policy themselves and the different status which sub-national units have in different countries, as well as their resopnsive capacity. (Goldsmith and Klaussen: 1997)  These persisting cultural differences are important in understanding the variable geometry of the EU.
The Operation of EU Regional Policy:
EU regional policy has operated in two different senses – formal, in terms of the definition and use of the structural funds, and informal, by which we refer to processes designed to amend the operation of regional policy, and ways in which the Commission in particular has sought to develop the regional level. First, however, we need to understand the Commission’s interest in both these matters.  As I have argued elsewhere, (Goldsmith: 1993) the Commission’s interest in working with sub-national governments derives not just from the formal objectives and imperatives of integration, but also from informal objectives and poliical processes. At one level the Commission works with sub-national governments because it needs information on policy needs and processes as an alternative to that provided from national governments and from other interested parties. Indeed different directorates of the Comission have themselves sponsored a large number of networks and activities which bring sub-national governments into contact – with many of them being only to willing to take up these opportunities, giving rise to a form of clientelistic rlelationship at times. Not only do these networks provide an opportunity to exchange information, they provide an opportunity for the Commission to introduce new policy experiments.
Second, the Commission faces problems of implementation of its policies.  Despite cries and complaints about the Brussels bureacracy, it remains small, and very dependent on others for implementation. Whilst implementation is often seen as the responsibility of  national governments, in many cases detailed implementation is decentralised to lower levels of government or other agencies. Given that one major way through which both integration and policy development effectively takes place is through regulatory processes (Cram: 1997; Majone: 1996; Wallace and Wallace: 1996; Young and Wallace:2000), then it is through the implementation of regulations and directives that such changes occur. Policy arenas such as environment, consumer protection and trading standards, contracting and transport all provide examples of areas in which EU regulation has been important and where sub-national governments have had  the task of securing compliance with the new regulations.
Within this context, how has EU regional policy operated? The highpoint was during the Delors years, from the mid-eighties until the late nineties. Using the structural funds, the Commission has been concerned from mid-eighties onwards to reduce regional and social disparities within the EU. Our concern here is with the use of two funds – the European Social Fund and the European Regional Development Fund[vii], since these were most applicable to sub-national governments. Before 1988, these funds were largely used to fund nationally determined projects, though some Commission initiatives ( Interreg and the integrated developed projects for example) were both more European wide and began to bring about a direct relationship between the Comission and sub-national governments. Reform of these funds led to the introduction of co-ordinated multi- annual programmes designed to promote economic development in the poorer areas of the European Union, using as a criteria for defining such regions the standard NUTS scheme to classify regions and taking as the poorest those with a GDP below a defined level for the Euroepan average (75% in the first case). Different levels of funding were then attached to those areas who qualified under the classification for funding – those who were identified as Objective 1 regions receiving more funding than those in Objective 2 areas, who in turn received more than Objective 5 areas. The reform of the structural funds greatly increased the amount of EU funding going to support  these elements of  cohesion policy – doubling in the period 1987 to 1993, and doubling again for the period 1994-1999 – or 32% of the EU budget by the end of the second period.[viii] Significant funds to play for, and as good grantsmanship players, those eligible quickly joined the game.
Furthermore, there were two further reforms or shifts in the policy. First, the funds were designed to promote economic development rather than supporting  large-scale infrastructure development and investment incentives, including significant funding for training and technology transfer. Second,  there was an important change in the decision making and implementation arrangements for the use of the funds. The new decision making arrangements supported the idea of partnership between the different actors involved. In other words rather than simply giving national governments  what were effectively blank cheques to support naitonally determined initiatives, the post 1989 use of the funds required proposals to come forward on the basis of an agreed strategy between national governments and the eligible regions, and at the regional level the funds also required partnerships between the public and private sectors along with the voluntary sector where appropriate. [ix] Such changes meant that sub-national governments (especially regional but also city,county and municipal) became legitimate actors in this game, a process reinforced by the adoption of the subsidiarity principle at Maastricht in 1992, which also recognised the importance of sub-national governments in the process by offering them consultative status through the Committee of the Regions[x](Tommel: 1998).
Not surprisingly, in addition to those regions located in the poorest part of the EU, (Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Southern Italy and Spain), significant other regions came to be included – especially as Objective 2 regions were to be found in those areas most heavily hit by the process of industrial re-structuring associated with economic change in the early eighties – mainly those regions linked to such industries as coal, steel, shipbuilding and textile manufacturing in countries like Belgium, France, Italy, and UK. After the re-unification of Germany, former east European areas such as Saacshen Anhalt became eligible for funding, and post 1995, parts of Finland, Sweden and Austria were also identified for funding. In addition, with the growing use of INTEREG arrangements, as well as funds for Objective 5, other areas found themselves playing on the European stage – and recognised the need to organise themselves to do so effectively.
Thus early in the nineties two developments were becoming apparent. At the national level, some regions were better at the game than others –thus for example in the UK it was Glasgow, Birmingham, later Manchester and Liverpool, amongst the cities which learnt the new rules and appreciated the game quickest, whilst regionally Scotland and Wales were better at exploiting the funds available than were parts of England. Elsewhere, quickly on the scene were the ‘Four Motors’, (Rhones-Alpes, Baden-Wurtemburg, Lombardy and Catalonia), seeking to establish themselves at the economic heart of the new Europe (Kukawka: 1996). Simlarly Lille and Nord Pas du Calais took advantage of Objective 1 funding and of the INTERREG rules to link up with Kent in England to exploit the building of the Channel Tunnel, whilst Dutch municipalities on the border of the country also exploited INTERREG. Barcelona exploited its status as an Objective 1 area to secure extensive funding to assist the developments necessary to hold the Olympic Games in 1992. (Morata: 1996). Wallonia in Belgium, together with coal mining areas in Britain, Lille in France also benefited from their activities in the Coal Communities Campaign, which sought support successfully from the Commission to help regenerating the dying coalmining areas of Europe.Outside the Objective 1 and 2 , it was areas like Cornwall in Britain which were to the fore in exploiting Commission funds, as well as those associated with the Atlantic Arc, the large number of regions and municipalities from Portugal to Ireland whose coastlines bordered the Atlantic, who, although not eligible for large amounts of funding, recognised by working together they could obtain support and recognition of their needs within the wider Union as early as 1989. (Brouard: 1996; Guesnier: 1993; Smith:1995)

By the early nineties, cross EU sub-national groupings were beginning to emerge, such as EUROCITIES ( a grouping of second cities across the EU); the Asssociation of Euroean Municipalities and Regions, as well as more narrowly based bodies such as RETI (originally cities and regions based on traditional industries, but who now stress their technological and innovatory strengths) and MILAN ( a motor industry network) were coming into being. And like all good pressure groups, individually and collectively, they recognised that under Delors the Commission was where much of the action took place – and thus that Brussels was the place to be. The nineties saw a rapid growth in the number of offices opened in Brussels by cities and regions across the EU and by their associations.  They quickly developed a  working relationship with the various Commission directorates – who  themselves recognised the growing importance of the structural funds as possible resources for their own initiatives – so that they worked with those who were also seeking to exploit the funds for their own purposes. And these groups quickly realised that if they could influence and shape  the agenda rather than reacting to it or simply seeking early warning of new developments, then the opportunity arose for them to shape policy so that it suited their ends rather than those of others. By the mid-to late nineties, estimates suggested that there were over 160 such offices in Brussels (John:2001, 87)
Of course it is possible to overestimate the importance of these developments. Brussels, as the centre of EU activity was and is a honeypot for those seeking to influence policy. In this respect the city has the same village like qualities as Washington, as groups exchange gossip, information and trade influence and ideas. Sub-national governments were only one such category of interest groups amongst many to be found there.  And, as we have noted, the Commission and its directorates generally welcomed them, founding, linking, helping such networks to flourish[xi].

By the mid to late nineties, this activity had reached its peak. People began to talk as if Delors’ ‘Europe of the Regions’ was in place. The new Committee of the Regions had been established and was offering its opinions formally on a wide range of issues. Regions, counties and cities across Europe were involved at the sub-national level in developing a series of partnerhsips to exploit the structural funds, and national governments were having to recognise this change. And many such sub-national governments were beginning to engage in what some authors have called ‘paradiplomacy’ (Aldecoa and Keating:1999) - that is to say establishing offices in Brussels and joining in bi or multi lateral discussions/relationships with their opposites across Europe, and joining European wide bodies such as AERM and EUROCITIES. To the fore of this development were the Lander in Germany; Flanders and Wallonia in Brussels, as well as Catalonia in Spain. Scotland and Wales were also present. In the case of the German and Belgian regions, these were permitted to represent their country at Council of Ministers meetings (Jeffrey: 1997; Kerrelmans:2000).[xii] Nevertheless, change was afoot: Amsterdam in 1996 was the turning point.
Amsterdam resolved – at least in the mid-term – arguments amongst the member states about how  the EU should develop in future. First, if the creation of the Single European Market; the adoption of the subsidiarity princple and regional policy had been about closer Euroepan integration (deepening the EU),then the quesiton of extending embmership to countries in central and east Europe was about widening the EU. Second, member states were showing signs of the increasing costs of financing the EU, a problem not entirely resolved by the accession of three new members – Austria, Finland and Sweden – in 1995. Third, the enlarged post 1995 Union was faced by continuing problems of decision making in the Council of Ministers and the need to extend the principle of qualified majority voting. Fourth, as the most expensive elements in the EU budget, both  the CAP and regional policies were due for review. In the light of the Amsterdam decision to widen  rather than deepen the EU, and to do so at minimum cost to the EU budget, both these latter policies were likely to suffere financial cuts. Additionally, as the Comission’s DG 16 in charge of regional policy gained more experience in the implementation of regional policy, it was beginning to change the rules of the game, tightening up the decision making processes and setting tougher targets and auditing programmes more carefully.

In such a context, it was perhaps inevitable that the post 1999 form of the structural funds would be different and that regional policy would be effectively downgraded amongst EU policy priorities, reflecting the fact that policy arenas rise and fall in importance.  Though both the Committee of the Regions and both transnational organisations representing regional interests fought to retain regional policy funding levels, as did several national groupings, their success was limited (John and McAteer: 1998). The Committee of the Regions had little impact and little influence (McCarthy:1997), specialist groups, such as RETI perhaps a little more, since their efforts were at least partially encouraged by DG 16,  itself seeking to retain its place in the sun. In the end, whilst regional policy remained in place, as did the Objective One areas (albeit with tougher criteria to meet), the post 1999 situation effectively redefined the boundaries of Objective 2 areas so that they covered larger territory, and with funding which was designed to aid their withdrawal symptoms over the next few years.
A variety of reasons can be advanced for this change. First and foremost was the general weakness of sub-national governments within the EU policy and decision making structures overall. Despite the appearance of influence and stature, they were always dependent on the support of national governments and their agendas, as well as on that of the Commission, which itself was enjoying an unprecedented role in EU decision making in the late eighties and early nineties. In part the change was a step back from the new multi-level governance and also a clearer recognition of the continuing importance of the dominant position of the nation state in EU decision making. The position of the Commission was not helped by the scandals which surrounded it in 1998 and the wholesale resignations of commissioners, the latter demanded and achieved by the European Parliament, which itself was seeking to test its own powers.
More simply perhaps was the fact that sub-national governments themselves varied in their capacity to operate on the European level, singly and collectively.  Not all regions, cities and municipalities were equal to the task – either organisationally, or in terms of their leadership and interest in things European (Goldsmith and Klaussen: 1997; Bache and Jones:2000). Those generally well-known regions and cities which had adapted early to the game, had benefitted from the structural funds over time, still operate at the EU level – but for how long? If the money goes away, what would keep them as players at this level? And what do these changes mean for the nature of EU integration, Europeanised policy making and multi-level governance, and for the future shape of territorial politics in Europe?
Some concluding remarks:
At one level the answer to some of these questions is simple – not all that much.  At another level, the answer is more complicated.  To take the simple answer first, the processes of EU policy and decision making will continue, albeit in a context of a changing balance of power between the participating institutions and changing rules of the decision making game.  What we have seen since Amsterdam is a re-assertion of the dominant position of national governments in the EU decision making processes and a change in their priorities at the Council of Ministers…widening rather than deepening is its simple expression. But the routines of policy and decision making continue across the board and not just for the major issues with which the Council of Ministers concerns itself.
In such a context, sub-national governments continue to be involved, though perhaps not on the same scale as when cohesion policy was at its height. Most importantly, as the Commission and the ECJ continue to produce continuing directives, regulations and decisions, the burden of implementation on sub-national governments is likely to increase rather than diminish, and across a range of policy arenas.  Siimilarly the arrival of new members of the EU from central and east Europe will, as several commentators have noted (Goldsmith:2000; John 2001: 91), provide new opportunities for the mobilisation of sub-national governments within the EU – indeed expectation of such events has already produced some such developments, generally encouraged by the Commission.[1]
But at another level, the answer is more complicated. Even though it has moved forward towards being a more bounded political system, the EU remains a weakly linked system by comparison with other (federal) systems in Europe and North America. In this context it shares more in common with national federal systems in Europe in which it is the intermediate tier which remains relatively powerful – as is the case in Germany, Austria and Switzerland. It is these national levels which determine the speed of formal political integration in Europe, whilst the process of Europeanising public policy arenas brings about a process of informal integration – in the sense that differing elites become accustomed to the process of working together and learning from each other. For sub-national governments, it may well be that the cross-national learning process is almost as important as the finance they receive, though undoubtedly the latter helps.
Such a process brings about the exchange of values and ideas about how politics works, challenging established orders and practices. These changes are largely incremental and slow, and national characteristics and values remain predominant. At the sub-national level, not all things are equal or the same, but the frame of reference within which a proactive region or city operates in Europe has been one set on a European and international scale as such places seek to maintain or improve their position in the world economic hierearchy.  Whilst some regions, cities and municipalities choose to remain as they are or feel incompetent or impotent in the face of widespread change, others tackle change head on and in colalboration with others. What Balme and LeGales (1997) called the ‘bright stars’ adapt and change and in so doing they bring about change in the way in which local politics operates in Europe, so that old distinctions between North and South in terms of welfare systems, modes of operation (clientelistic versus non-clientelistic) are no longer as valid as they were ten or twenty eyars ago. (Goldsmith:2000; John: 2001).
What is clear is that the experience of working within Europe for many cities and municipalities has changed the way they operate. Traditional cultural imperatives which led to the distinction between Northern and Southern political styles are no longer quite as important as they were: cross national experience leads cities and municipalities to think about and do things differently. The examples of the Four Motors, the Atlantic Arc group, as well as the many INTEREG cooperations simply mean that regional and local governments are increasingly aware of different ways of doing things. Notwithstanding the funding made available under the structural funds, the Commission and its directorates also encouraged extensive exchange of experience, distribution of best practice and considerable cooperative working amongst sub-national units on a trans-national basis (see inter alia Hingel: 1993). Extending the EU into central and eastern Europe simply brings more players into the game at all levels, putting traditonal values and methods under even greater pressure.
This is not to suggest that change is rapid or that old distinctions are no longer valid. What it does do is to suggest, as authors such as Keating (1997), Goldsmith (2000) and John (2001) is that territorial politics throughout Europe is in a state of flux. In other words territorial politics within Europe and inside the EU are unstable, changing, and likely to remain so for the forseeable future.
In the process of globalisation and Europeanisation, national governments, as well as those operating at sub-national levels, have learnt that singly their influence is limited, and that they are largely dependent on collaboration with others to achieve change.  The EU is not about hierarchies, but about networks and interdependence in an ever-changing environment. Some of these networks are extremely formal, reflecting the operation of the formal institutions of the EU, whilst others – especially in the policy areas – are often far less formal, and in many ways no less important. In this sense EU governance is supranational.
Explaining this European system of governance – giving it a theoretical basis – continues to challenge social scientists. The different models – state centred, intergovernmental, multi-level governance – all have at least descriptive validity of the processes and relationships which they seek to explain. In so far as the EU continues to be dominated by discussions amongst member states at the national level; in so far as the EU institutions such as the Commission, Parliament and the ECJ  continue to be weak, and in so far as effective formal decision making depends on the acceptance of new treaties at the Council of Ministers, then the state centred model remains valid. And in so far as policy and decision making processes reflect hierarchical relationships between the Commission, national governments and sub-national units, involving a process of bargaining and negotiation between the  different levels, then intergovernmentalist approaches have validity. And in so far as these relationships involve informal networks cross-cutting the hierarchies and national boundaries, then the multi-level governance approach provides insights.
To describe the processes as one involving variable geometric relationships is both insightful and arcane. It is insightful because the phrase captures the very essence of an almost constantly changing set of relationships over time[xiii]. It is arcane in that because we do not fully know the rules and principles underlying the geometry, so that we lack a sound  theoretical basis for understanding the EU, its political insitutions and its politics. In this concept the need for new concepts and ideas remains imperative (Marks et al: 1996; Scharpf: 1999; Rosamond:2000;  Hooghe and Marks:2001).




[1]  Such activity is part of the preparation for future membership.  Before Austria,  Finland and Sweden joined the EU in 1995, they had been involved in a number of  EU activities. Yet their degree of preparation was variable – Finland quickly active in Brussels and its networks, Austria and Sweden less so.


[i]  Some authors place considerable weight on the process of Europeanisation of policy as a sign that a supranational form of governance is emerging within Europe – see for example Sandhotlz and Stone Sweet (199). This author prefers to maintain a distinction between formal integration, as evidenced through the treaty processes and acceptance of European Court decisions, and a more informal process of integration through the Europeanisation of public policy within the EU, as well as other more informal social processes –travel, cultural, educational which EU citizens increasingly enjoy.
[ii] Again it is important to distinguish this process from the emergence of a supranational set of institutions, as associated with authors such as Stone Sweet and Sandhotltz (1998). The author returns to this question in the concluding section.
[iii]  The extent to which this process has developed is well brought out by Fligstein and McNichol (199).

[iv] The crisis in the air carrier industry following the September 11th 2001 terrorist attack on New York City is a good example, with several large national carriers seeking EU financial aid and national governments seeking EU permission to support their own national carriers.

[v] The author is very aware that the globalisation is neither new nor complete – see for example Hirst and Thompson (1996) . Nevertheless, these general trends are sufficiently forceful to encourage a process of adaptation at all territorial levels.  For an example of how far territorial politics in Europe are indeed fragmented and changing see Keating (1997).

[vi]Whether this goes so far as to establish an EU constitution is debatable – see Shaw (1999) and references cited therein for a discussion of this point which is outside the scope of this chapter.
[vii]  As Hooghe (1996:3) rightly notes, three funds were involved – the Agricultural Fund underpinning the Common Agricultural Policy was the third. For a discussion of the regional impact of the CAP see Dudek C (2001).

[viii]  These figures do not take into account either a special cohesion fund designed to help the four poorest countries between 1994 and 1999, nor additional monies set aside to assist with the integration of  Austria, Finland and  Sweden from 1995.

[ix]  For a detailed discussion of these changes and their operation until the mid-nineties see especially Hooghe L (ed) (1996a)

[x]  The impact of this new body is discussed briefly below.
[xi] The author has some personal experience of this activity. In the mid nineties he chaired a pan EU network made up of universities, chambers of commerce, regional and city governments and technology transfer/innovation centres under the RETI umbrella, which was able to benefit on several occasions from Commission largesse.
[xii]  Even in highly centralised Britain, following devolution  Scotland has on occasion taken its places at the Council of Ministers. (Foreign Office spokesman: 6th November 2001).
[xiii]  For an interesting and stimulating discussion in this respect see Chryssochoou (1997)

No comments:

Post a Comment